Introduction – ARMA models and behavior of multiple components
Time series models of the typical
ARMA family should be viewed as a tool to tell ourselves stories about how time
series behave. They focus us on the question of primary importance - how will the shocks be propagated into
future and hence influence future values – and allow us to answer it in
simple terms. For example autoregressive model with high coefficient tells us
that effect of shocks will be eliminated only gradually and hence propagated
over long period of time. On the other hand moving average models of low order
tells us that the effect of shocks will disappear quickly. Or finally, moving
average model with negative coefficient tells us that the recent shocks will
have opposite effects in near future.
This simple pallet of models is
very flexible and allows us to capture most of the behavior of real world
series. One particular place where it can be applied is in thinking about
detailed consumption and production series influenced by the pandemic (think
purchases of cars or box office sales). In principle, these series can be
thought to be composed of at least 4 components, 3 relating to lockdowns (or
more broadly social distancing) and one to the overall economic shock.
The three components related to
lockdowns effect capturing the effect of lockdowns which prevent
consumption/production; effect of pent-up demand after lockdowns are lifted
(i.e. most people who very planning to purchase car will still do so sometime
after lockdowns); and effect of substitution, as money saved on some regular
expenditures due to lockdowns are spend on some other items due to
impossibility of time-substitution (e.g. people will not catch up with all
their regular cinema and restaurant visits they have missed). The other
component is component capturing effects on confidence and/or expectations
about current/future incomes, i.e. the usual component we see in recessions,
albeit this time the bad news arrived in more time-compressed manner.
These components behave very
differently from each other. Moreover, not all series contain all components,
and even if they do, these components might behave differently for different
series (think of more persistent lockdowns/social distancing effects for most
sensitive industries). This means that in contrast to normal recessions there
will be much bigger heterogeneity across individual consumption series.
Moreover, the first three are very unique to our current situation and their
novelty together with their complexity means that we can easily get confused by
temporary movements. It should be therefore worthwhile to consider the different
options we might encounter over the next few months and what it means for
behavior for given series. Below are few examples.
Example 1 – Spending on restaurants: Pure lockdown shock with no pent-up demand and substitution
The first example applies to
series which is affected by the lockdowns, but does not benefit from the
pent-up demand and substation effects. An
example could be spending in restaurants – restaurants in many countries were
closed for most of April and to a lesser degree May and June, so that the
spending in restaurants is substantially lower in these months. At the same
time, people will return to restaurants as soon as their re-open, so that July
should be back to normal level of spending (or close to that). The graph below
translates this discussion into deviations from normal level of spending (left
chart) and into growth rate of the series (right chart). The magnitudes are illustrative
and not meant to be representative.
Turning to the way this is
captured in the standard time series ARMA models, the profile in the chart is
achieved by using MA(2) process with single (negative) shock in April. The
moving average model extends the effect of shocks for the number of periods
corresponding to the order of the process, in our case two extra periods.[1]
Intuitively (but not necessarily), the coefficients on lags of shocks are lower
than 1 so that the effect of the shock decreases over time. Of course, the
length of the shock effect as well as its strength in each period can be easily
changed with the order of the model or the size of the coefficients: moving
average models give us complete flexibility over this, albeit at a cost of
possible overparametrization.
An alternative to lengthening the
effect of shock through increasing the order of moving average model is to use
autoregressive model. AR models eliminate effects of shocks gradually,
multiplicatively.[2]
Therefore, in contrast to MA models, the effects of shocks persist for more
periods than is the order model. In case of our lockdowns we can think of
lasting lockdowns for most dangerous industries, say restaurants focused on
international tourists (or similarly international air travel). Picture below
captures such situation:
Of course we could combine moving
average and autoregressive models to get ARMA model, which combines the profile
of responses in first and second pictures:
Note that the different three
options of lockdown effect profiles translate into slight, but important
variation in growth rates we should observe. In first case large drop is
followed by immediate and rapid growth for 3 months. In second case the growth
is still immediate, but it is not rapid; instead the recovery is spread over
many months. Finally, in the last case the growth is not even immediate but
actually comes with some delay.
Turning to econometric
calibration, what we have added is AR(2) process for confidence. As before, we
can see that the autoregressive model makes the effect last very long: the
confidence component is negative throughout the whole year. Moreover, AR models
of order higher than 1 with first coefficient bigger 1 also feature
amplification: the peak effect occurs with delay. Therefore, the confidence
component is largest in absolute value in June, two months after the initial
shock. Finally, the sum of the coefficients is very close to 1, so that the
effect of the shock is eliminated very slowly and even at the end of the year
it is close to its maximum size.
Of course, things could be easily
re-parametrized. We could ensure that the peak effect is either sooner or
later, and we could ensure that the elimination is faster or slower. This could
be done either within the context of AR(2) model, so would not require
additional parameters, or by changing the order of the model. Examples of two
re-parametrizations are below:
Therefore, the difference between
autoregressive and moving average processes is in terms of trade-off between flexibility
and over-parametrization: autoregressive process can give us some flexibility
for given number of parameters, while moving average processes can give us
infinite amount of flexibility at cost of many parameters.
Finally, all the charts above
assumed that ¾ of the impact we observe in May is due to lockdowns and rest due
to demand effects. Of course, for different consumption series different
distribution will make sense: for other industries it will be mostly demand
shock and bit of lockdown shock (spending on newspapers); for some it will be
more equal; and for some there might be even a negative lockdown shock (think
purchases of food in grocery stores).
Example 2 – Spending on cars: Lockdown shock with pent-up demand but no substitution
The second example applies to
series which is affected by the lockdowns, but after lockdowns are lifted it
benefits from the pent-up demand (but not from substitution effects). An example could be spending in cars – car
dealerships in many countries were closed for most of April, so that the
spending on cars is substantially lower in that. At the same time, most people who
were planning to buy car will do so soon after lockdowns anyway irrespective of
the pandemic. Such situation is captured in next chart:
Here the crucial thing is to
realize, that the pent-up demand gives us temporary small boost in the May (and
even smaller in June), so that the rebound is faster than before. After June
the profile is again determined solely by the confidence component and hence is
identical as before. There is one even more important realization: since the
pent-up demand gives us temporary boost in terms of level, there is actually
decline in the spending in June, even though the June deviation from normal is
smaller than before. This highlights the problematic nature of growth rates in
coming months.
In terms of econometric
calibration not much has changed: lockdown and confidence components are as in
original case, while pent-up demand component is moving average model as the
lockdown. The way things have been specified is using the same error as in
lockdown equation and set current-period coefficient to zero, which is rather
unusual. Nevertheless, this is for simplicity: one could write this down more
elegantly, but it would blunt the message the pen-up demand is just partial
reversal of lockdown shocks.
Example 3 – Spending on home-improvement: Lockdown shock with pent-up demand and substitution
The last example applies to
series which is affected by the lockdowns, but after lockdowns are lifted it
benefits from the pent-up demand as well as substitution effects. An example could be spending on home
improvement – this was impossible during the lockdown since hobby markets were
closed for most of April, so that the spending on home improvement is
substantially lower in that month. At the same time, most people who were
planning to do such home improvement will do so soon after lockdowns anyway
irrespective of the pandemic. And on top of that, since people saved money on
some regular expenditures with which they do not plan to catch up – think no
tourism, restaurant visits or cinema outings – they decide to use left-over
money for home improvements. Such situation is captured in next chart:
The picture resembles the previous case but the rebound is even stronger in May, so that the deviation from normal actually turns positive in this month. However, once the temporary positive effects dissipate the confidence effect takes over and the series goes back below normal. The growth rate in this situation is even more strangely looking than in previous case – after drop there is even larger jump, followed by large second drop before stabilization. Hence, growth rates do not tell useful story almost at all.
Econometrically, we have added
another moving average process very similar to pent-up demand, so there is
nothing new in that sense.
Conclusion – More caution than usual needed
Given the nature of the shock the behavior of individual
consumption series will vary greatly. This divergence reflects the fact that in
current situation – in contrast to normal recession – series can be thought of
as composed of several differently-behaving components. This then can play
havoc in how individual series will behave: not only will there be large swings
in growth rates, there might be also multiple switches from positive to
negative growth rate. This highlights how growth rates can be very misleading
in coming months. While level will certainly be more informative, one can
imagine reversals even here. So the overall message is that one has to be
cautious when drawing conclusions from individual consumption series in coming
months.
[1] Of
course, one could argue that what is really happening is three successive
shocks, but this distinction is relatively slight in current situation. The
notion here is that the effects of lockdowns always linger for some time, so
that they can be described by some firm process.
[2] In
the simplest case of AR(1) model, say with coefficient 0.9, 10% of the previous
period effect is eliminated in each period.
[3]
Note that the April impact is the same as before, just that part of it is
demand shock. This is true throughout this document.
No comments:
Post a Comment