For decade-and-half since 2007, most of the action in terms
of euro zone monetary policy was focused on the so-called unconventional
policies. First came the liquidity infusions in summer of 2007, which were
gradually enhanced and culminated in the switch from fixed allotment to
full-allotment policy in the fall of 2008. With the onset of the euro zone
sovereign debt crisis then came the asset purchase programs related to the transmission
of monetary policy, namely the Securities Market Program and Outright Monetary
Transactions program. Finally, the low-inflation period starting in 2014 lead
to introduction negative deposit rates and targeted long-term refinancing
operations (TLTROs), and culminated in systematic asset purchases under the
Asset Purchase Program.
For now, the shift to normalization of monetary policy also meant
shift away from unconventional and back to normal policy instruments: the
interest rates. After the asset purchases have been discontinued in first half
of this year, and TLTROs are no longer expanded, the central bank started
raising all it policy rates. Already the first hike ended the 8-year long
policy of negative rates, and by the end of this year the policy rates will in
all likelihood be approaching something what can be considered normal or
neutral levels.
However, this does not mean that the other policy
instruments will not be tampered with. Indeed, there are reasons to believe
that the central bank will take steps that will reverse some of the
unconventional moves taken in the past, some of which will have potentially
important implications for monetary policy stance. True, any change in strategy
regarding the stock of assets purchased during last 10 years is unlikely in the
near term. Instead, the central bank might take two actions that were not part
of the usual tightening cycles before the Global financial crisis: It might
make asymmetric moves in policy rates, and it might take step that will
directly or indirectly alter the renumeration of excess reserves.
Spreading the policy spread
Before the Global financial crisis the world of central bank
policy rates was pretty simple. There was the main refinancing rate (MRR), at
which bank could borrow from the ECB during the regular tenders. It was the
main policy rate influencing market interest rates, hence its name. The other
two policy rates – the deposit rate (DR) and the lending rate – were 1
percentage point above and below the MRR, respectively, and always moved in
lock-step with the MRR.
This all changed in the following years. First, in the world
of excess reserves, which emerged in 2008 and remained with us since, the MRR
was no longer the “main” rate, since the deposit rate became by far more
important for market interest rates. So much so, that by now the MRR is almost
irrelevant and all the focus is on DR. Second, from 2013 the spread between MRR
and DR was no longer the fixed one percentage point, but rather the central
bank started changing rates asymmetrically. First, the spread between the two
was decreased in 2013 and 2014, reaching low of 0.25%, and then it was increased
again, reaching high of 0.5%.
During its first hike in July the ECB moved all rates in
lock step, mostly in order to keep things simple. However, this does not mean
that the central bank cannot change the spread between the two rates, and there
are reasons to think it might. For example, during one of the fall meetings it
could increase the MRR more than the DR, in order to increase the spread back
to the presumed desired long-term level of 1 percentage point. This would have
the additional advantage that the bank could portray this as step up in the
inflation fight. Importantly, in reality this would not amount to significantly
faster tightening of financing
conditions. Indeed, it would virtually not amount to any tightening at all, much
like cuts in MRR in 2013 did not amount to any easing as far as market rates are
concerned. Hence, it would be a PR victory without any real costs. This could
even play well with the dynamic inside the governing council, as the doves
could use it as a concession to the hawks without worrying about undue impact
on the economy. This reasoning suggests to us that we are likely to see such
move during one of the upcoming meetings.
Ever heard of negative re-numeration?
The other unusual move we are quite likely to see is a
change in renumeration of excess reserves, something the bank has already
hinted in its July meeting. However, in this case the situation is much more
complicated fraught with risks, and the motivation here is purely in terms of
political optics.
Up until now, the central bank was renumerating any excess balances
with the deposit rate. Prior to Global financial crisis this renumeration
amounted to almost nothing, given that banks faced powerful incentives to not
hold any excess reserves. Afterwards, when the deposit rate went to zero there
was no renumeration whatsoever.
When the ECB moved to negative rates, it turned the
renumeration principle on its head: Rather than paying commercial banks when
they had excess reserves, it started charging them, by making the deposit rate
negative (and shutting down avenues to avoid this). This was combined with
large-scale asset purchases under the Asset Purchase Program, which resulted in
large amount of excess reserves being infused into the system. As a result, the
ECB was pocketing huge profits: not only was the bank earning interest on its
assets, at least as long as those remained positive, which on average they did.
But it was also pocketing huge sums thanks to its liabilities being
“renumerated” with negative interest rate. It is as if you borrowed money from
a friend, invested them at profit, and yet your friend would be paying you for
lending you money.
This was putting a strain on the profits of commercial
banks, which is why the central bank introduced tiering of excess reserves
renumeration in fall 2019, when it restarted asset purchases. This way, it kept
the pass-through from deposit rate to market rates intact, while not raising
worries about commercial banks solvency.
Re-labeling excess as required
Of course, this is all going to change when deposit rate
rises above 0%. This will mean that the ECB will be paying money to commercial
banks, rather than receiving money. With excess reserves standing at 4
trillion, this would amount to tens of billions of euros as soon as deposit
rate would rise significantly above 0%. Unsurprisingly, the central bank is
thinking about how to avoid this. Not only it would hit its profit, turning it
from positive to negative. More importantly, it would amount to very bad
politics: The headlines would be full of stories about commercial banks getting
money from the central bank, something very unpleasant in normal times, and
much less so when everybody is undergoing unprecedented cost-of-living crisis.
The problem is how to go about this. Consider first the
option of raising MRR without raising DR. While this sounds great in theory, in
practice it would defeat the goal of raising market interest rates, which now
respond only to movements in DR. So this is not an option in so far as the ECB
wants to tighten policy stance. This leaves as an alternative avenue only two
options: changing the amount of excess reserves by re-labeling them as required
reserves, or changing how excess reserves are renumerated.
Start with the first option. The central bank could easily
just say that banks are suddenly required to hold much higher level of reserves
by changing what is called the reserve-requirement ratio. This currently stands
at 1%, meaning that bank needs to have reserves equal to 1% of its deposits. Changing
this ratio is not unheard of. It used to be an active policy tool in western
world in the last century, and the emerging markets central
banks, such as central bank of China uses is to this day.
There are problems with this approach, though. First,
increasing the reserve ratio would mean that the market interest rates would
move away from the deposit rate. Since as the amount of excess reserves would
decrease, and since the spread between money market rates and deposit rates is
negatively related to amount of excess reserve, this would lead to an increase
in this spread. Hence, this step would amount to tightening of monetary policy
stance. Moreover, this tightening would be hard to calibrate, and the central
bank could easily overdo things. This is especially true given that the
increase in reserve ratio would be very large for it to have meaningful impact
of ECB profits.
However, potentially more important than this average effect
would be the distributional effect. The excess reserves are not distribute
among banks equally, so increasing the reserve ratio would cause some banks
suddenly to be short of reserves, leading them to need to borrow reserves from
banks that still have excess.
What is the problem with this, given that this was normal
before the Global financial crisis? Mainly, that we are in a very different
world already for more than a decade. Ever since the Global financial crisis
banks became unwilling to lend to other banks out of fears about solvency.
Moreover, as amount of excess reserves increased, there was a less and less
need for banks to borrow. Hence, effectively there hasn’t been any
lending/borrowing of reserves on significant scale for more than a decade, and
it is far from clear how would banks respond if the need arose.
This is especially problematic because the banks with lower
reserves are likely geographically concentrated in the euro zone periphery.
Putting pressure on these banks could quickly lead to re-emergence of fragmentation
in the monetary union, something the central bank is desperate to avoid. It
could even spill into the bond markets, as periphery banks could try to sell
their bond holdings to raise their reserves.
So overall, it is fairly unlikely that the ECB would choose
this as its main approach. This, however, does not mean that the bank would not
use this approach on the margin. An obvious step would be for the bank to
increase the reserve requirement ratio at least to 2%, where it stood prior to
2012, but possibly more, say mid-single digit levels.
De-numerating the re-numeration
This leaves the other approach of changing how excess
reserves are renumerated. There is a clear precedence for this in the tiering
introduced in 2019. At that time the ECB followed the Bank of Japan and allowed
part of the excess reserves to be renumerated by 0%, rather than the negative
deposit rate. Like that the ECB lowered the total amount commercial banks had
to pay to it without changing the marginal rate, i.e. the rate that applied to
the last euro of excess reserves. This meant that the effect on market interest
rates was almost nil.
The central bank could put this logic on its head. Rather than
allowing balances below certain threshold to be renumerated by 0%, it could mandate
that balances below some threshold would be renumerated by 0%. While this
sounds almost identical, the difference is that while before it was 0% instead
of negative deposit rate, now it would be 0% instead of positive deposit rate.
What would be the implications of this move? To see this,
consider situation of two commercial banks - one with excess reserves below the
threshold and one with excess reserves above - when deposit rates were
negative. The one with excess reserves
below threshold was paying zero interest on its reserves, while the other one was
paying interest on balances above the threshold. In this situation the bank
with lot of excess reserves had incentives to lend them to the other bank, and thus
lower its bill.[1]
The other bank meanwhile was willing to do that because it would still pay
zero, as long as it stayed below its threshold. This dynamic had the added
advantage from the perspective of the ECB, since it shifted reserves from banks
in the core to banks in the periphery, a desirable change in fragmented
monetary union fighting low inflation.
Now consider the same situation when deposit rates are
positive. The commercial bank with excess reserves below threshold would be
earning zero interest on its reserves, while the other one would be earning reserves
on balances above the threshold. This is the flip side of the situation we
observed before, but this time it creates incentives that are also reversed.
Rather than pushing reserves from banks with high balances to banks with low
balances, this time around it would create incentive for excess reserves to be
pushed towards banks with high balances.
The banks with high excess reserves would have incentive to
borrow from banks with low excess reserves as long as the transaction rate
would be below deposit rate. Meanwhile, the banks with low excess reserves
would have always incentive to lend, since earning positive interest is better
than earning 0%. Indeed, banks below threshold
should be willing the lend all of their excess reserves to other banks, and
keep only the amount required, while banks above threshold should be always
willing to borrow.[2] And
this is a potential major flaw of this design, because it would cause
bifurcation of distribution excess reserves, with some banks holding large
amounts and some banks holding zero. While before there was a stable
equilibrium where all banks were close or above their threshold, this time the equilibrium
is unstable. Any bank that drops below threshold would have incentive to
decrease, and any bank that jumps above threshold should be willing to
increase.[3],[4]
What about the aggregate effects on market rates? In world
of negative deposit rate the effect of tiering on market rates was almost nil,
since there remained incentive for reserves to be lent out at rates close to
the deposit rate, with banks with low reserves borrowing from banks with high
reserves. This kept market rates anchored by deposit rate. This logic would
still remain true, as banks above threshold would have incentive to borrow as
long as transaction rates would remain below deposit rate, and competition over
available excess reserves would ensure that market rates would still remain
anchored to deposit rate.[5]
As the deposit rate would rise, the market interest rates would follow. That
said, the anchoring would be from below, potentially significantly so, and
hence from perspective of market interest rates this would amount to easing of
policy stance.
Therefore, the distributional effects are clearly
problematic - especially in currency union where these redistribution effects
are not irrelevant -while the aggregate effects are not. Where does this leave
the ECB? In principle, it could ignore the problematic distributional effects in
order to achieve its mostly political objective. In practice, the ECB would
likely try to have its cake and eat it too. It could do this in two different
ways. First, it could set the threshold so low that most banks would remain
above, so that almost no banks would have real incentive to de-accumulate
excess reserves. Or it could set another threshold over which excess reserves
would not be renumerated, so that there would be only a band in which full
renumeration would apply. However, to make sure that this would not prevent
market rates being anchored by deposit rate, it would have the remain the case
that at any given time there are is significant number of banks withing this
range.
In either case, the discussion shows that this approach is fraught with calibration issues, which means
that we would not be surprised by the central bank avoiding this minefield
altogether. That said, some action is clearly going to occur, the question is
how significant it will be.
Not rocking the boat full of bonds
What about ECB’s assets? In contrast to asymmetric changes
in policy rates and changes to renumeration of excess reserves, we are not
likely to see any activity on the front of the stock of asset purchased in last
decade. This is despite the fact that the one option the ECB has in this regard
- letting the portfolio mature without re-investments over time – would help
with the problem of paying banks large sums.
The motivation is clear here. The normalization of policy
rates is already making bond markets skittish, sending fear up the spine of the
ECB. This creates very powerful incentive for the bank to avoid rocking this boat
any further. Indeed for now the ECB is using re-investments from the Pandemic
Emergency Purchase Program as first line of defense against volatility in bond
markets by selectively re-investing the proceeds into periphery government
bonds. There is little reason the central bank would want to give up this
nimble tool and instead add to the fire ending these re-investments. For these
reasons, no action on this front is on horizon.
[1]
More true description of reality is probably focusing on other avenue of
changing amount of excess reserves, namely buying assets, rather than lending
out excess reserves. When commercial bank buys an asset from another commercial
bank, it pays it in form of its reserve balances, what then achieves the same
outcome of redistributing excess reserves from one bank to another.
[2]
Again, more likely avenue through which this would operate would be via asset
purchases/sales, see previous footnote. Bank with excess reserves below the
threshold has opportunity cost of excess reserves equal to 0%. In contrast,
bank with excess reserves above threshold has opportunity cost of money equal
to (now positive) deposit rate. Hence the first bank should be more eager to
buy assets than the second bank, leading the first bank to (indirectly) buy
assets from the second bank, which would eventually lead to the same
redistribution of excess reserves as lending between the banks. Note that while
in world of negative deposit rates the incentives were for the banks in the
euro zone core that were rich in excess reserves to buy assets, this time it
would be the banks in periphery that would have incentives to buy assets. This
might be undesirable.
[3] Of
course, bank just below the threshold might decide to make the decision to go
increase its reserves just above the threshold. That said, since this is uneconomical
– it needs to accumulate some reserves for which it gets 0% interest, rather
then lending them out at above 0% interest – it would apply only to banks close
to the threshold.
[4]
Note that in practice, there would be other limits to this behavior. The
lending banks would face limits imposed by credit-risk rules, which limit how
much exposure to single entity should bank have. The borrowing banks might face
limits with respect to their size, either in form of liability-to-equity ratio.
But the general tendency would hold.
[5]
This is the situation in the U.S. where some financial institutions have access
to the deposit facility, while others do not.
No comments:
Post a Comment