Saturday, November 20, 2021

Reminder: Price setting is a coordination game

 Inflation is the main topic of macro discussion right now, with price increases exceeding expectations, even after accounting for the additional shocks. As usual, the media focus is on the situation in the U.S., but the phenomenon is pretty much global This means that other countries can offer us some clues on the nature of the phenomenon.

One such country is Czechia, which combines features that make it an interesting learning case. On one hand it is a country with firmly established inflation targeting, so that it is not plagued by the regular instability of inflation expectations that haunt many emerging markets. This means that its experience is relevant for central banks in developed economies, unlike experience in, say, Brazil or Turkey. On the other hand, it is a small open economy with significant focus on industrial production. This means that its experience is not only sufficiently different from US or euro zone, but that it is more exposed to current sources of inflationary pressures than these countries.

So what is the recent inflationary development in Czechia? Simply, inflation is running amok: prices have increased by around 1% in each of the last 4 months. That is,  increase of 4% in span 4 month. Or to put in yet another way, it is the increase central bank desires in a two-year period occurring in four months. While the sources are to some degree global, such large increase cannot be explained by these factors alone. And before one jumps into conclusion that this is result of domestic policy mismanagement, it is important to note that the government support for the economy was not abnormal – apart from decrease in income tax benefiting mostly the rich – and that the economy is actually doing quite badly relative to its peers.

So what is the lesson here? This is speculative, but one way to think about the situation is in terms of what we know about the incentives for price setting. Increasing prices is in its nature a coordination game: each firm does not want to raise its prices in order not to lose customers to its competitors. This is what lies behind sluggishness of price adjustment in economic models.

But what if everybody knows that everybody will be increasing prices because of spike in input prices such as commodity prices, energy prices, component prices etc.? Well, if price setters know that their competitors will be increasing prices now, and that they will need to increases prices relatively soon anyways, then they might as well decide to increase prices right away. After all, higher prices are less likely to be noticed in environment when everybody is increasing prices.

This means that the rapid price growth might be result of coordinated equilibrium: everybody increasing prices because they observed public signal that everybody will be increasing prices. And as such, some of the price increases we are seeing might be prices increases brought forward, causing inflation to spike more than one would expect. In other words, we might be seeing a year worth of price increases crammed into several month in which everybody expected everybody to hike prices.

This means two things. First, in the short term inflation is likely to surprise on the upside even more, with other price setters jumping on the inflationary bandwagon. Second, the inflation might drop relatively quickly: once the period of rapid price increases is over, further price increases might not be forthcoming, since they have been brought forward. In some sense, we will have reached the natural level of prices, just in different path, with rapid inflation followed by quick slowdown in inflation, rather than gradual rise we are used to. Of course, the second observation applies only if the inflation does not cause change in inflation expectations, in which case rapid inflation could start to feed on itself.

 

This pattern might even fit the historical experience: it seems that commodity-driven inflationary periods which did not result in shift in inflation expectations are often followed by long periods of subdued inflation. Most recent example is the example of inflationary spike in 2011, and long years of low inflation afterwards.

 

P.S.: Note that this is one example of why the Calvo pricing is so not up to the task: it does not allow firms to choose when to change their prices, only by how much, and hence does not allow for coordinate price increases.

P.P.S.: In terms of time series modelling, this would suggest that the price level, not just its part rate of change, is important. Or alternatively, that there are more regimes in inflation.

P.P.P.S.: There is a notion of attention-driven inflationary behavior in here: maybe individual price rises are less likely to be noticed when they are done in environment of many prices rising.