Friday, March 10, 2023

Is it or isn’t it a recession?

On regular basis we are now having discussion in Europe whether “something” is or is not recession. Inevitably, these discussions lead to conclusion that while we started talking about the aspects of that “something”, the discussion is really about “what is recession” rather that whether this particular something is a recession. In other words, the discussion we need to have is what constitutes a recession, rather then discussing the details of the economic situation.

Czechia example

Consider the example of Czechia. Here are the facts:

  • GDP has contracted for two quarters in a row, each time around 0.3% non-annualized. It is still below its pre-pandemic peak.
  • Consumption has contracted for 5 quarters in a row, cumulatively 7.6%.
  • Fixed investment has decreased in last quarter as well, albeit after strong recovery throughout the previous year and a half.
  • The reason why GDP did not drop more is because net exports surged from their extremely low values reached during the pandemic period. In last quarter government consumption also helped a lot.
  • Despite all the weakness, labor market is tight, with unemployment rate close to its pre-pandemic historical lows (in case you don’t know, it is ridiculously-sounding low at 2.1%).

Is this a recession? In many dimensions it is. I mean, 7% drop in consumption is simply gigantic; for comparison, during great recession, there was almost no contraction. Now it is accompanied also by drop in investment. And then there are the two successive declines in GDP, which would qualify as recession according to the silly definition for “technical recession”. On the other hand, the 0.6% drop in GDP is far-cry of normal recession. And above all, it just does not feel like recession here on the ground. It just feels like pretty depressing period for consumers.

Are there recessions in RBC models?

Yesterday, my boss had an interesting idea. Maybe we should look at things like defaults and bankruptcies, rather just macro aggregates, when determining whether something is or is not recession. I then built upon that idea further and to put focus on self-reinforcing demand shocks as the key aspect of recessions.

To see this start with following question: Are there recession in RBC models? The question of recessions was one of the first controversies between proponents and opponents of RBC models. The reason was that RBC models explained fluctuations in output as fluctuations in the productive capacity of the economy, rather than output falling below such productive capacity. This led to the classical critique question of “What are the productivity shocks”, as declines in productive capacity required negative productivity shocks. Such shocks were at odds with the understanding of productivity at the time, given that productivity was understood as akin to technology or knowledge. (By the time I was reading this discussions I was not that puzzled: if you think about productivity more broadly it feels very natural that it could easily decrease following a shock; an example below).

Therefore, RBC models did and did not feature recessions. They did in the sense of output declining in some periods of time. But they did not, in the sense of output being below its (short-run) potential. I.e. there were no output gaps. Only the move from RBCs to new Keynesian models allowed for this possibility more broadly - albeit for a long time only to a limited extend – by introducing nominal rigidities which could give rise to demand driving the decline in output. And I think this contrast in perspectives is actually very useful for current situation.

Real shocks and demand shocks

To see how the perspective of real shocks vs demand shocks is useful now, consider back the case of Czechia. How can we explain the current economic developments? I think it I fair to say that the economy is undergoing large real shocks, both positive and negative. On the negative side, the surge in energy costs is a very large and - crucially – real shock, in that it changes the productive capacity of the economy. Moreover, at this point in time it also leads to redistribution of output away from consumption, which to some degree might be optimal. Meanwhile, the reason why output did not collapse more is because at the same time the economy also faced large positive real shock in form of global supply bottlenecks unwinding, which in turns I just reversal of previous large negative real shock. (All of these are examples of negative productivity shocks, since productivity and technology are separate).

What is crucial, though, is the fact that these real shocks have so far not been accompanied by negative demand shocks. In the words, the typical mechanism though which recessions are self-reinforcing – drop in demand causing further drop in demand through various channels – has not kicked in. This can be seen in things like firms not firing people or aggressively cutting down their orders and slashing inventories in response to uncertain demand environment. It can be seen in that the financial channels being so far very silent: there hasn’t been a wave of defaults leading banks to curtail the supply of credit. Simply, while both consumers and firms are being hit by shocks, they have not started worrying about the outlook in a way that would cause them to change their behavior above and beyond what the shocks require.

No recession – but what is it then?

And this is why I don’t think Czechia is in recession. Neither is any other European country so far. Simply, a recession really requires a demand shocks to occur, and they have not occurred yet. I mean this in the sense that demand is so far only responding to the real shocks hitting the economy, and is not additional source of shocks, at least not to a significant degree.

Of course, what is not yet the case might soon come to be: there is nothing that says that firms will not lose their faith as their order books are depleted and start slashing their demand and laying of people. And if that starts happening, then it could gain speed pretty quickly. But in absence of this happening, the economy will proceed along its current trajectory, struggling to generate much growth before the effects of real shocks start to reverse. Will the resulting path be a recession? I don’t think so. At the same time I am sure it will not be fun either. Seems like we need a better terminology.

P.S.:  Was pandemic recession a recession in this view? I would say yes, because there was a demand component. Financial channels were very alive and kicking. Firms like car producers slashed they demand for inputs expecting slow demand from their customers. Sure, the demand was not the dominant factor, which is why the recovery from the recession was very different from great recession. Of course, the main reason why demand played limited role is because of the demand management: fiscal and monetary policy prevented collapse in demand and actually gave additional boost to demand. But that is another story.

Sunday, January 22, 2023

Can we enter recession without layoffs?

On recent episode of Inside Economics podcast, there was a question raised whether we can get recession without layoffs. There are two parts to this question: Can we enter recession without layoffs, and can we go through recession without layoffs? I think the latter is pretty hard to achieve and it would require very mild recession, at which point it is a question whether given period actually amounted to a recession or not. It the former question which is more interesting.

So, can we enter recession without layoffs? I think the answer is not only “Yes”, but that we have already had such experience. Consider a following pair of pictures capturing labor market aggregates (first picture) and GDP with unemployment rate (second picture) in particular historical period. (On purpose I omitted the date axis, which will be revealed at the end, but bonus points for guessing it outright 😉) .




The second half of this period was officially categorized as recession. This is not very surprising as during this time monthly hiring has declined significantly from 5.2m to 4.5m, dragging down with it the employment, which has declined by 1.7m from 138.4m to 136.7m. Meanwhile, unemployment rate increased from 4.7% to 6.1%, while GDP had two quarters of negative growth intersected by a positive quarter. Overall, this is clearly consistent with recession, albeit not a particularly severe one.

The key point, though, is in the layoffs series, replicated once more with slightly extended sample:



While layoffs did increase a bit, the increase was very small amounting to 200k-300k, less than half of decline in hirings. Moreover, this increase occurred only towards the end of our sample. Before layoffs did not record any increase (at best they were bit elevated) while employment already managed to decline by 0.5m.

The conclusion is simple: we have already had an experience when we entered recession without widespread layoffs. Therefore, even if firms will hesitate to lay off people – something that I think will be a feature of potential 2023 recession – we might enter recession in 2023. All that it would take would is for firms to significantly decrease their hiring, something that is possible even if they will be hesitant to let their current employees go. In such situation employment will start to decrease and unemployment rate will start to increase, eventually tipping us into recession. And then the layoffs will likely come. (Indeed, one can imagine that if we do tip into recession, then the eventual layoffs might become more aggressive then initially thought, given that firms will be postponing layoffs for long period of time.)

So what was the period of time captured in the pictures? It was the onset of Great Recession:



Of course, after the end of the picture employment continued to tank as hiring decreased further, and more importantly, layoffs increase:



The other way to see the argument is to look at the cumulative effect of each of the flow category on the overall employment:



This shows that hires were initially the predominant source of shortfall in employment and that layoffs really kick in only in late 2008. Hence the conclusion that high layoffs are not necessary for unemployment to rise and for us to enter recession, low hiring will suffice. That said, given that this picture is quite sensitive to the choice of base date – layoffs were somewhat elevated in November 2007 already relative to say 2006 - a more qualified statement would be that large-scale layoffs are not necessary, low hiring and slightly elevated layoffs will do.

This is because even in normal month there is large amount of churn, with lot of laid-off people who quickly find new work, as long as hiring is robust. If it is not, then people who will be laid off as part of natural process, will not find work and will become unemployed.

P.S.: Someone might argue that this whole period might not have been classified as recession unless the financial crises escalated in September 2008 (official declaration came only in December 2008). That is possible, even if not very persuasive, given that employment decline was gathering pace already in the summer. 

Saturday, January 21, 2023

Addendum to ‘The power of choice of transformation, part 3’

When I was going through my rant about why year-over-year growth rate is not a good transformation for this period of volatile macroeconomic data, I might have made it look that I oppose it only during this period. In reality, I quite dislike year-over-year growth rate most of the time.

My biggest pet peeve is how is it used in news to indicate whether something has contracted or not in a given quarter. Take, for example, the Chinese GDP during 2022, shown in terms of level (blue) and in terms of growth rate:

 



It is obvious that Chinese GDP experienced two quarter when in contracted, that is second and fourth quarter of 2022, dropping by 2.7% and 1.1%, respectively in quarter-on-quarter terms (not shown here). Yet, in both quarters the year-over-year growth rate remained positive, effectively thanks to the accumulated growth in previous quarters.

And then comes a newspaper writer and writes “Chinese economy avoided contraction in second  quarter of 2022”. Come on, how useful and correct is that?! What really annoys me is the terminology "in given quarter here". There is no way to characterize the experience as avoiding contraction in given quarter, because within that given quarter there was a contraction. The absence of contraction in terms of year-over-year growth rate is about the other 3 quarters...

But oh well, I know that this just me insisting on words having a proper meaning...